Economic Price Optimization Part 3 – Mental Models Matter

timjsmith

Tim J. Smith, PhD
Founder and CEO, Wiglaf Pricing

Published April 1, 2013

In Freshman Land, economic price optimization can be done with simple models and equations.  But Freshman Land doesn’t reflect reality, and hence we have to move to the next level.

In two prior articles, we examined standard models for price optimization taught in freshman economics.  In both cases, these models yielded some fruit, but proved questionable when it came to actually identifying prices.  One major fault with both of these models derives from a common shortcoming, and this shortcoming can be overcome.

Simplistic Models:  Insightful but Not Necessarily for Pricing

In Price Optimization with Globally Linear Demand — Both Useful and Useless, we demonstrated that modern thinking on corporate strategy can largely be derived from basic economics.  Specifically, we reached the conclusion that all competitive advantage derives from exploiting a rare and inimitable resource that enables a firm to deliver greater value at a lower cost to its customers.  This is a significant accomplishment and should not be overlooked.

However, this conclusion is not what most executives think about when they think of economic price optimization.  Instead, they think of it as a concrete and self-sufficient method for pricing.  And we have seen that this simplistic approach is useless when it comes to actually pricing a product or service.

In Economic Price Optimization with Locally Measured Elasticity of Demand — Unreliable, we demonstrated that a firm’s pricing power is a function of the elasticity of the market it serves.  More specifically, firms serving relatively inelastic markets—markets where customers are relatively price insensitive—are able to raise prices and improve profits, while firms serving relatively elastic markets—markets where customers exhibit high price sensitivity— are unable to raise prices and may need to lower prices to increase sales volumes.  For this reason, firms seeking pricing power should seek to reduce their customers’ price sensitivity, and this usually implies the firm should seek to increase its customers’ sensitivity to differences in benefits.  Again, this is a significant accomplishment and should guide strategy decisions.

But that broken ground should be taken with a grain of salt, as we also showed that direct measurements of elasticity are bounded by uncertainty, and therefore the optimal prices derived from this method are most appropriately described as a range rather than a precise number.  Since this range can be very broad, the usefulness of this approach is unreliable.

Identifying the Shortcoming

A common shortcoming shared by both of these derivations is in their model of demand.  Economic price optimization relies upon an accurate depiction of the market demand function.  Neither of the above approaches uses a demand curve that is observed in actual markets.   They may approximate demand curves for small changes in price, but they do not describe the real, observed demand curves.

Real markets don’t generally face a linear demand function, like that shown below.  While a downward sloping straight line represents the fact that demand normally increases as price decreases, and simple straight lines are easy to work with in deriving proofs and demonstrating concepts, they don’t capture the full beauty and complexity of market behavior.

Linear_Demand_Function

Similarly, markets don’t generally face a power-law demand function, with curves like that shown below.  The assumption that elasticity is part-wise constant may be true for small changes in price and quantity sold, but this assumption doesn’t describe the observed demand at all prices for any market known to me, and probably not any market at all.  Elasticity is useful for describing the market’s reaction to a small price change, and therefore managerially useful for evaluating the potential for a small price change.  Yet while this model is useful for small price changes, it isn’t the best approach for describing the market’s reaction to all possible prices.  In fact, it is generally the wrong mental model to use when trying to describe the full range of prices possible.

Constant_Elasticity_Demand_Function

Describing Firm-Level Demand

We need a better model of demand.  Fortunately, we have one or two.  But first, let’s think about how real markets react to real prices offered by firms.

Please note:  I am examining firm-level decisions in competitive markets, not “the whole market”-level issues.  I am doing so because I wish to address the challenges faced by real executives that manage real businesses, not economists or governmental agencies describing and regulating entire industries.  As a point of clarification for classically trained economists:  you may wish to think of this as the decisions of a firm engaged in monopolistic competition moving to the extreme of perfect competition.  This does describe most real firms in real competitive markets under free-market capitalism as it is practiced today.

Maximum Prices

For a firm serving customers in a market with competitors, there is a price so high that it can expect all of its customers to abandon it and choose to purchase from a competitor.  Let this be defined as Pmax.  At any price above Pmax, the firm’s demand drops to zero.  At a price below Pmax, at least one customer will purchase something.

Minimum Prices

For a firm serving customers in a market with competitors, there is a price so low that it can expect all customers to purchase from it, with all competitors losing their business.  Let this be defined as Pmin.  At any price below Pmin, the firm’s demand increases to reach the full demand of the entire industry.

In competitive markets, Pmin is likely to lie at a point below variable costs.  That is, it is likely to be so low that the firm cannot sell at that price and make a profit, and since it is the price at which competitors won’t sell either, it is likely to be below the minimum variable costs of even the most efficient competitor.

Since the firm makes no profits at Pmin, and is likely to achieve losses at Pmin, no rational firm should choose to price at Pmin.

The Range in the Middle

At a price between Pmax and  Pmin, some customers will purchase from the firm and other customers will purchase from competitors.  This is the range of prices where a firm usually operates.

The demand function that we would want to use to describe the market’s response to prices between Pmax and  Pmin is some smooth function that describes the case of zero demand at Pmax and the entire industry demand at Pmin.

There are two commonly used functions that meet these goals.  Most economists and marketers use the cumulative beta distribution function.  Some use the cumulative normal distribution function.  In either case, they produce demand curves like that shown below.

Realistic_Cum_Beta_Function_Demand

Price Optimization with a Realistic Market Demand Function

Now, given this demand function, where should a firm set prices?

Economic price optimization can be done with this model for demand and produce reasonably useful results after making appropriate measurements of various parameters required for defining the demand function.  The math behind such an approach is the same as that described in our prior two articles, but the equations get rather long and intractable with pencil and paper.  As such, it is common to program a spreadsheet or software system to identify the optimal price for a given product and market.

Still, I cannot suggest this method as the best starting place for every pricing decision.  For most pricing problems, there are more efficient and accurate approaches that start not with an abstract model of market demand but rather with concrete data gathered from customers and prospects regarding their perceptions of differential benefits and willingness to pay.  For others, we find we want precision around a point rather than precision for the market overall.  Which implies, that while this model of demand is superior to the linear or constant elasticity model, it still isn’t perfect.

If the above demand curve can be used for subset of pricing problems only, what does it reveal to the rest of us?

Three key concepts are revealed through the describing demand with a cumulative beta or cumulative normal distribution function

Number One:  Shoot High, Explore Low

If a product has to have one list price for the market, where should it be on the Observed Firm-Level Demand Function?  High.

Consider that most firms practice discounting.  Discounting is a good method for exploring demand at prices below list.  As a rule, a well-managed discounting policy enables to the firm to capture marginal sales at marginally lower but still profitable prices.  Since discounts are made from higher list prices, and since discounting can enable the firm to price an offer selectively for certain customers,  we come to the conclusion that list prices should be set high on the demand curve while discounting policy is used to explore lower price points on the demand curve.

Number Two:  Most Firms Don’t Sell Commodities

If someone claims their market is being commoditized, examine the range of prices in the market before you accept their claim.

In a fully commoditized market, the difference between Pmax and Pmin is zero.  Using economic speak, one would say “Under perfect competition, all firms are price takers.  The industry-clearing price is the one price all firms must accept to be in the market.”  (No wonder freshmen have a hard time understanding economic textbooks.)

Now most firms see some difference between the price at which demand collapses to zero (Pmax) and the price at which they could capture the entire industry (Pmin).  The size of that difference, the difference between Pmax and Pmin, is a measure of the commodity nature of the industry.

Not that there are hard rules about this, but one can pretty safely state the following:

  • If the same product is sold by multiple firms and the difference between the maximum price and minimum price of the product in the market is less than 5%, then that product is a commodity.
  • Alternatively, if similar products are sold by multiple firms and the difference between the maximum price of a product and minimum price of a product within the category is more than 50%, then that product is a not a commodity.

Some markets, like oil, wood, chemicals, gasses, and vitamins, are best described as commodity markets.  In these markets, the difference between Pmax and Pmin is very small if not effectively zero.

Most markets however have a wide range of prices and products within the category.  Just consider the price difference between Relic and Philippe Patek watches, Kia and Mercedes cars, or Nokia and Apple smartphones.  Differentiated offering markets can see price ranges with a difference greater than 1,000 times between the lowest- and highest-priced product within a category.  These price differences directly reflect the non-commodity nature of these markets.  And if the highest-priced transaction in the market is only 50% higher than the lowest-priced transaction in the market, I still would have a hard time rallying behind calling that a commoditized market.  There is still room for price differentiation.  Just look at Vulcan Materials – even they can charge different prices to different customers for something as common as dirt and rocks.

Number Three:  Mental Models Matter

Many people like the idea of using economic price optimization to set prices, but it isn’t as simple as identifying a number and plugging it into the model.  That is the wrong mental model.

The key to pricing lies in understanding market demand, understanding what customers want and what they will pay for it, understanding that no two customers are alike and that each may have a different willingness to pay.  And for that, there are many methods and no one approach solves all pricing problems.  Not data analysis, not surveys, not interviews, but all of them and each for their own pricing challenge.

Firms don’t confront a linear demand function. They don’t even confront a demand function where the elasticity is relatively constant at different prices.  They confront a demand function bounded at the top and at the bottom with some range in which prices should lie.

Posted in:
Tagged: ,

1 Comments

  1. Stewart on August 4, 2013 at 8:00 am

    I agree with your premise – a few additional observations
    Most companies spend little time considering their economic model, choosing instead to use the resource allocation process (budget) to somehow flush this out
    Understanding how costs, different types of business, seasonality, and constraints interact with revenue to generate margins over the medium and long term are at the heart of the economic value of the business
    Systems/processes that rely on a static elasticity are by definition wrong most of the time – a wrist watch that is right twice daily



About The Author

timjsmith
Tim J. Smith, PhD, is the founder and CEO of Wiglaf Pricing, an Adjunct Professor of Marketing and Economics at DePaul University, and the author of Pricing Done Right (Wiley 2016) and Pricing Strategy (Cengage 2012). At Wiglaf Pricing, Tim leads client engagements. Smith’s popular business book, Pricing Done Right: The Pricing Framework Proven Successful by the World’s Most Profitable Companies, was noted by Dennis Stone, CEO of Overhead Door Corp, as "Essential reading… While many books cover the concepts of pricing, Pricing Done Right goes the additional step of applying the concepts in the real world." Tim’s textbook, Pricing Strategy: Setting Price Levels, Managing Price Discounts, & Establishing Price Structures, has been described by independent reviewers as “the most comprehensive pricing strategy book” on the market. As well as serving as the Academic Advisor to the Professional Pricing Society’s Certified Pricing Professional program, Tim is a member of the American Marketing Association and American Physical Society. He holds a BS in Physics and Chemistry from Southern Methodist University, a BA in Mathematics from Southern Methodist University, a PhD in Physical Chemistry from the University of Chicago, and an MBA with high honors in Strategy and Marketing from the University of Chicago GSB.